RECENT ARTICLES

 

 

Attacking Wall Street with a Blunt Instrument

Roy Smith

 

(Financial Times, January 7, 2003)

 

The recent announcement by securities regulators and Eliot Spitzer, New York attorney-general, of a Dollars 1.4bn (Pounds 870bn) settlement with 10 prominent securities groups for misconduct is a disturbing event for those who seek clarity and fairness in stock market regulation.

     The settlement purports to punish leading investment banks for engaging in systematic exploitation of investors and to provide needed reform by tighter regulation of the relationships between analysts and investment bankers, by changing public underwriting practices and by requiring Dollars 450m in subsidies for independent research to be provided to retail customers. But the settlement has been extracted by threats of criminal prosecution by Mr. Spitzer and by continued public exposure to embarrassing staff e-mails and other leaked communications. The 10 groups were divided into different tiers of culpability and put under pressure to pay up (two smaller companies refused to settle and were deferred). The companies did not admit to any violation of laws or regulations and the records of the case will presumably be sealed from further public view. The government has greatly disproportionate power over Wall Street groups in confrontations such as this and can impose a solution that may not be fair. Indeed, this global settlement invites the thought of companies being rounded up in the midst of a public scandal because of where they rank and then all lumped together under bright lights for a show trial.

     As in a number of cases last year - the Securities and Exchange Commission against Credit Suisse First Boston and the state of New York against Merrill Lynch - this settlement does not make clear what the groups did that might have been in violation of existing laws or regulations. How do you prove that a research report is fraudulent rather than wrong? While it is clear that during the years in question the market experienced the biggest bubble in history, and some analysts were taken in by their clients and/or were poorly supervised and given excessive inducement to bring in new banking clients, it is not clear that the effort was systemic or that the attributable level of harm and injury to retail customers in particular rises to the level of a Dollars 1.4bn fine.

     On the face of it, a fine of Dollars 1.4bn would suggest an egregious, clear and deliberate breaking of existing rules simultaneously by 10 leading investment banks. Could all of these - in fierce competition with each other - have knowingly issued false research recommendations to gain business? Would not their more sophisticated corporate and institutional clients have learnt of it and objected?

     If it can be shown that what was done was against the law, the individuals concerned and their companies - when appropriate - should be punished accordingly. If that cannot be shown, a forced group settlement for conduct that is not clearly in violation of law or regulation is unfair to the banks.

     The reform measures of the settlement are unnecessary and expensive. Mr. Spitzer, the central figure in securing the settlement, has no business affecting details of federal securities laws. These are administered and enforced by the SEC and SEC rules already cover most of the ground that Mr. Spitzer's reforms address. True, the SEC has been headless and dysfunctional for some time. But that does not give Mr. Spitzer a licence to insist on new regulations to reform the markets, particularly only a month or two before the new SEC chairman takes office.

     Each effort to layer more regulation on the market has a cost and that cost is ultimately born by market users. In addition to huge fines and the likely need for further settlements with the ever-present plaintiff bar, the added costs of providing subsidised independent research and other provisions of the settlement begin to add up. At some point issuers and investors may find that regulatory costs are much greater in the US than elsewhere.

     America’s markets work well because information flows effectively and relatively inexpensively.  Companies value broad distribution of new issues to include institutions and individuals alike, both of which require post-offering information about the companies. Their bankers require expert analysis of private companies before taking them public. Analysts are the people who supply this information to the market; if they were not needed, they would not exist.

     We do not want reforms to damage the efficient flow of information or to ignore the cost of additional regulation to the users of the market. Group settlements for the sake of establishing scapegoats are not the way to regulate a complex, sophisticated global securities industry.   (Download pdf)

 

* * * *

 

O'Neill's Resignation Offers Opportunity

 

(Newsday, December 8, 2002)

 

Roy C. Smith

 

 

 

Since the administration of Franklin Roosevelt, America has had 11 presidents and 20 treasury secretaries. George H.W. Bush had one, but Presidents Harry Truman, Dwight Eisenhower and Jimmy Carter had two each, Presidents John F. Kennedy and Lyndon Johnson together and Presidents Ronald Reagan and Bill Clinton had three. Together, Presidents Richard Nixon and Gerald Ford appointed four.

     Though the turnover of secretaries of state and defense is comparable during the last 11 administrations, the treasury secretary has often been the senior Cabinet member who was least well known to the new president - someone whose appointment was urged on by political advisers and with whom the president had not developed a comfortable relationship. Nixon hardly knew David Kennedy, his first appointment. Likewise, Carter hardly knew Michael Blumenthal, Reagan hardly knew Donald Regan and George W. Bush hardly knew Paul O'Neill, who resigned Friday. But these were not ordinary Cabinet appointments. The treasury secretary is the most visible member of the administration addressing economic policies - policies which are crucial to the success of any administration. So, naturally enough, he is the one who has to take the blame for unsatisfactory economic performance.

     O'Neill's departure offers his boss an important opportunity to bring in new faces and fresh approaches to achieving better results from unpopular or stalled initiatives. Often the second or third guy in the Treasury job has been recognized as one of the most effective members of the

administration he served - Henry Fowler (Johnson), George Schultz (Nixon), James Baker III (Reagan) and Robert Rubin (Clinton). But whether or not Bush can turn O'Neill's resignation into an opportunity depends on who the new appointment is and what sort of policy shift is likely to follow.

     So far, the Bush administration has spent its economic capital on a tax cut to return much of the expected fiscal surpluses of a few years ago back to the folks who provided them, as well as some anti-free trade tariff increases and the restoration of extensive farm subsidies that were cut out in the Reagan days.

     Though since then the economy has softened and the surpluses have disappeared, unemployment has reached the 6-percent level again, a war on terrorism has been declared and there may soon be an invasion of Iraq, the economic message from the White House seems to be that all the economy needs now is to make the earlier, slow-acting tax cuts permanent to boost consumption and to reduce the tax on corporate dividends to perk up the stock market.

     Today's economic reality, however, dictates that the new man or woman in the Treasury get a grip quickly on two policy areas that may already be out of control - the growing danger of huge federal, state and municipal fiscal deficits in the years ahead and the need to plan more thoroughly for the cost of wars against terrorists and those countries that we deem to be harboring them or developing weapons of mass destruction.

     Congress may regard the federal budget as an unlimited source of spending for pork once again, but the president has the power to stop it by vetoing bills that are not sufficiently frugal. The direct costs of warfare and military occupation in the Mideast are likely to be very large - this time borne mainly by the United States - and they need to be part of the planning process that leads to spending limits. Even then, the indirect costs of military operations can be even more serious if these begin to affect commodity prices and bring about a renewed battle with inflation, as happened during the 1970s when the economic consequences of the war in Vietnam were felt around the world, especially in stock and bond markets.

     These issues require a tough line from the White House, one that might offend the ideological base of the Republican Party and possibly toughen up the resistance shown in the future by Democrats. But one of the most important jobs that a treasury secretary has is to gain the president's confidence to force him to face the harsh realities that are out there now and to resist political motivations to give people what they want.

     Bob Rubin was reportedly very effective at playing this role with former President Clinton after he succeeded Lloyd Benson as treasury secretary. The Clinton economic policy appeared to change after Rubin was installed in the Treasury to place the highest emphasis on deficit reduction, which led to further lowering of interest rates, an extensive stock market recovery and several years of continued economic growth.

     President Bush has a chance now to do something similar - to focus on the deficits - and Paul O'Neill has given him that chance by becoming disposable. It has happened to a lot of treasury secretaries. (Download pdf)

 

* * * *

 

Strategic Directions in Investment Banking—A Retrospective Analysis

 

Roy C Smith

 

May you live in interesting times!

           —Ancient Chinese curse

 

     Few businesses have ever benefited, as the U.S. securities industry did, from the almost continuous eighteen-year economic and financial tailwind that occurred from 1981-1999. At a time when world and United States GDP increased at a compound (nominal) rate of 7%, U.S. and world equity market capitalization and trading volume all increased at about twice that rate. The worldwide volume of new issues of equity securities increased at 19% and debt securities at 25%. The volume of worldwide mergers and acquisitions also increased by more than 25% per annum during the period. During this time also, commercial banks, under pressure from bad loans and mismanagement and subject to intense competition, gave up vast amounts of deposits and assets to the securities market in a massive display of disintermediation.

      In such buoyant market conditions, it would seem to be difficult for any of the handful of American investment banks that specialized in capital market services to do poorly. In fact, however, the burden of managing such rapid growth effectively was a great one, and not all firms fared well. Indeed, for many once-great firms, the opposite was true. Drexel Burnham went bankrupt and Kidder Peabody was subject to a distress sale. So was First Boston, a casualty of bridge loans in the late 1980s that had to be reclaimed by its principal stockholder, Credit Suisse. Lehman Brothers and Smith Barney, then ailing, were sold, and reshuffled several times (in Lehman’s case, back to the public in 1994). Salomon Brothers, wounded from its illegal actions in the Treasury bond auction market in 1990, never fully recovered and was sold to a division of The Travelers Group. A number of other US firms that were generally thought unable to keep up with competition, including Dillon Read, Chase Manhattan, JP Morgan and Paine Webber, found merger with a stronger partner (although at a decent price) their best strategic alternative. (Download pdf)

 

* * * *

 

Capitalism Will Clean Itself Up

 

(Financial Times, April 11, 2002)

 

Roy C Smith and Ingo Walter

 

More financial wealth in America was created in the last two decades of the 20th Century than at any other time or place in the history of the world. A stupendous stock market boom boosted the value of financial assets at twice the rate of the economy’s nominal growth. Many boats rose in this extraordinary tide. As the new millennium dawned, nearly half of American households were participants in the stock market. Conspicuous consumption, private philanthropy, and political activism all followed the market’s boom. It was a great time and American corporations and financial markets became the wonders of the modern world.

     But the early years of the new millennium have seen an ebbing of the stock market tide. Although the Dow Jones index is off only about 13% from its all-time high, the NASDAQ index (containing most of the computer and telecom names) is down by more than 50%. And, the falling tide not only lowered the boats, but also revealed a lot of rocks and slime that were overlooked on the way up. The sudden collapse of Enron (and some other companies) revealed a dark underside to American corporate governance. Though management could be innovative, aggressive and glib (all useful qualities), it could also be misleading, dishonest and corrupt. Enron, for example, was able to contaminate all those who chose to fatten at its corporate trough—its directors, auditors, bankers, analysts, rating agencies, lawyers and political friends.

     Enron, however, was hardly alone in its accounting fiddles and dubious management practices. The list is as long as the trail of shareholder litigation and failed audits by the “big five” accounting firms. But Enron did much to sharpen sensitivity to financial shenanigans, so investors today are looking much more skeptically at all companies, including some of the country’s most respected firms. The growing concern about the integrity of American corporations dovetails with this year’s publication of top executives’ compensation awards, with plenty of examples of management self-enrichment despite declining earnings and eroding stock prices.

     How can this be, after so many years of attention to principles of good “corporate governance” and pontificating to others about the superiority of the American capital market-dominated system? In a recent address at New York University Alan Greenspan, Chairman of the Federal Reserve, said there are “hardly any independent directors left” on corporate boards, adding that our system has become CEO-dominant and difficult to restrain, and that mechanisms supposedly binding the interests of managers and shareholders sometimes do just the opposite.

     In the old days, corporate directors like banker J. Pierpont Morgan (as a representative of bond investors, not stockholders) imposed restraint on management and owners of large corporations. Companies feeling the Morgan presence often traded at higher stock prices than companies without it. But as corporations evolved into public companies financed in capital markets by fragmented shareholders and equally fragmented debt-holders, most of the power of restrain reverted to the managers themselves. In recent years, CEOs have been able to select boards supportive of their management, and have rewarded them for their loyalty. For CEOs determined to accomplish their goals, reservations on the part of outside directors (if any) have had little influence.

     Such a system inevitably must pay a price for lapses in effective governance. Managers may be allowed too easily to commit their companies to strategic mistakes. The methods used to compensate management have become absurd. They are paid to sign-up, paid to stay, even paid to go—often at eye-popping rates that bear no relation to the results achieved, while stock options are handed out with little accountability or regard for their dilutive effects—and then sometimes are repriced when they turn out to be temporarily worthless. Worse, smoke and mirrors appear to make implausible things seem to work, misreported accounting numbers obscure true performance and risks, and deals are encouraged just for the sake of showing dynamic acquisitive behavior (or maybe to increase the size of the CEO’s corporate platform, fame and personal fortune). Government can and does react to some of the worst offenses, but standards of proof are high in criminal cases and not all of them are addressed.

     But the pendulum inevitably swings back, and market forces emerge to cleanse the system. In a rising market, even those who are victimized fail to see many of the clues that things are seriously wrong. Reactions are delayed until a serious crack in the system opens. But when it finally comes, the market can extract a terrible price for unacceptable conduct. Enron’s stockholders lost all of their investment in a company that a year before had been worth well over $50 billion. Bank lenders and bondholders will have to forfeit nearly the same amount. Enron employees and pensioners with significant voluntary holdings in the company’s stock—some who might have been middle management whistleblowers but weren’t—lost their hard-earned retirement assets. Officers and directors have already taken heavy financial losses and forever have lost their good names—and there will be further losses as whatever is left of their fortunes is depleted by the many civil lawsuits they yet must deal with. Enron’s auditor, Arthur Andersen, is already a ruined hulk, whether it legally survives or not, and its partners will have lost a lifetime’s earnings retained in the firm. Most recently the shareholders’ lawyers have added nine of Enron’s bankers and two of its law firms to a growing list of defendants. Finally Enron’s equity and credit analysts have been embarrassed by their incompetence in finding catastrophic trouble, and face a future in which their recommendations are likely to be considered suspect, ignored or scorned. Those involved will not soon wish to repeat their experiences.

     The forces redressing the cumulative weaknesses in American corporate governance, however, do not stop at Enron. All of America’s 8,000 publicly traded companies will have to pay more for auditing services, and much more for officers and directors liability insurance. Stock prices of companies whose accounts come under suspicion will sag below their peers, and borrowed money will carry higher interest rates, punishing their cost of capital and competitive performance in the marketplace. Accounting rules will tighten and make it more difficult to overstate reality. The cleansing will take place because the market finally wants it to, and the market will get what it wants.   

     For critics of the American system of CEO-dominated corporate governance, correction by market forces may seem clumsy, awkward, uneven and unreliable. But it works, as no other system can, though admittedly its fury is released only after the damage is done. Most alternatives work against the market. This one works with the market to extract retribution, when enough is enough. (Download pdf)

* * * *

 

 

Rating Agencies – Is There an Agency Conflict?

 

Roy C Smith and Ingo Walter

 

This paper accepts the premise that an agency conflict does exist when rating agencies perform credit rating services that are paid for by the recipient of the rating. The question is to what extent is the conflict injurious or distortive? To examine the issue we analyze the benefits that ratings provide to investors, regulators and issuers. Ratings we find have greatest value when published, therefore becoming a public good to which free riders are inclined to attach. Investors become disinclined to pay for ratings, yet issuers, who can benefit considerably from a rating, are willing and able to pay the fees the agencies charge. The agency business has become quite transparent, especially with Moody’s becoming a public company required to disclose its business information to the public. There is relatively limited competition between the major agencies (Moody’s and S&P between them each rate about 80% of rated issues, and the ratings tend to be highly correlated with each other) so neither is inclined to take great risks to increase its market share, and Moody’s we find to be a very profitable company with approximately $4 billion of market value depending on its rating “franchise” value. It seems able to make satisfactory levels of profits without resorting to practices aimed at protecting profits. We found no evidence of rating distortion caused by shopping for ratings, no evidence of more favorable (i.e., higher) ratings being granted by the market leaders, nor evidence of agencies now or ever having offered favorable ratings for higher fees. Moody’s in particular is highly dependent on maintaining its reputation for integrity to protect its franchise value, and its ability to continue in business. Further, we find that the agencies are also much more exposed than most businesses to potential punishments of regulators and class-action litigants. In the end, there is reason to believe the rating agencies manage their built-in conflicts of interest with their customers well and that agency conflicts, to the extent they exist, are controlled.  (Download pdf)

 

* * * *

 

 

The Integration of World Financial Markets—Past, Present and Future

 

Roy C. Smith

 

Financial people know in their bones that their profession goes back a long way. Its frequent association with "the world’s oldest profession" may simply be because it is almost as old. After all, the essential technology of finance is quite simple, requiring little more than arithmetic and minimal literacy, and the environment in which it applies is universal--that is, any situation that involves money, property or credit, all of which are commodities that have been in demand since humankind's earliest days.[i]

         These financial commodities have been put to use to facilitate trade, commerce and investment and to accommodate the accumulation, preservation and distribution of wealth by states, corporations and individuals. Financial transactions can occur in an almost infinite variety, yet they always require the services of banks, whether acting as principal or as agent, and financial markets in which they can operate. Banks have predominately been local institutions throughout their history, but many have sought international expansion to follow clients abroad or to offer services not available in other countries.

         Banks have a long history: a history rich in product diversity, international scope and in continuous change and adaptation. Generally, change has been required to adjust to shifting economic and regulatory conditions, which have on many occasions been drastic. On such occasions banks have collapsed, only to be replaced by others eager to try their hand in this traditionally dangerous but profitable business. New competitors have continually appeared on the scene, especially during periods of rapid economic growth, opportunity and comparatively light governmental interference. Competitive changes have forced adaptations too, and in general have improved the level and efficiency of services offered to clients, thereby increasing transactional volume. The one constant in the long history of banking is, perhaps, the sight of new stars rising and old ones setting. Some of the older ones have been able to transform themselves into players capable of competing with the newly powerful houses, but many have not. Thus the banking industry has much natural similarly to continuous economic restructuring in general.


         It is doubtful, however, that there has ever been a time in the long history of banking that the pace of restructuring has been greater than the present. Banking and securities markets during the 1980s and 1990s in particular have been affected by a convergence of several exceptionally powerful forces--deregulation and re-regulation, disintermediation, the introduction of new technology and product innovation, cross-border market integration, and greatly increased competition and consolidation--all of which have occurred in a spiraling expansion of demand for financial services across the globe. Bankers today live in interesting--if exhausting and hazardous--times. In this chapter we will have a look how we got to where we are today, at the characteristics of the wholesale financial services markets in the early twenty first century, and some of the unresolved issues that will affect the industry’s future.



[i] This chapter is based on Chapter 1 of Roy C. Smith and Ingo Walter, Global Banking, (New York: Oxford University Press, 1997), pp. 1-16.

 

(Download pdf)