![]() |
After years of extraordinary growth, East Asia's emerging economies are showing signs of fatigue. Are they exhausted? Or just resting before springing forward again?
THE rapid expansion of the East Asian tigers--many by an average of more
than 8% a year over the past three decades--has provoked fear in the West
and pride back home. Never before in world history has any region sustained
such rapid growth for so long. The four original tigers (Hong Kong, Singapore,
South Korea and Taiwan) have almost joined the ranks of developed economies
in terms of GDP per head (Hong Kong and Singapore
are both richer than Britain, (see table)). China,
Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand have started to chase the leaders' tails,
though from much lower levels of income; and the Philippines (a slow starter)
has just joined the pack. But unprecedented rates of growth are not all
this disparate group of countries has in common.
In the past year, almost all them have come
down to earth with a bump. Export growth in East Asia was only 5% last
year--feeble compared with the roughly 20% growth achieved in 1994 and
1995. Malaysia, South Korea and Thailand are running current-account deficits
of 5-8% of GDP. South Korea has been disrupted by
strikes; stockmarkets in Bangkok and Seoul have plunged; and financial
systems through the region look wobbly. Singapore's GDP
growth rate fell to 5.8% in the year to the fourth quarter of 1996, down
from an average of 9.5% in 1994 and 1995. Average GDP
growth in the region slowed from almost 9% in 1995 to 7% in 1996--a rate
Americans or Europeans would die for. But industrial production in the
richest tigers, Singapore and Hong Kong, tumbled by 5% during that year.
Reactions to the slowdown fall into two broad
categories. In the first are the pessimists. They are unsurprised. They
thought Asia's rapid expansion was unsustainable all along because (they
claim) it has been based on massive inputs of capital and labour--and not
on gains in efficiency. To them the slowdown is structural. The tigers
were bound to seize up sooner or later; the recent figures show this happening.
The optimists, on the other hand, are unfazed.
They give little weight to the argument that something is structurally
wrong with the tigers. They reckon the growth of past decades has been
rooted in the wise policies of the governments and the profit-seeking behaviour
of the people. As for the recent showdown, they explain that away as cyclical.
Sooner or later, the optimists think, the cycle will turn and the Asian
miracle will start amazing the world again. As usually happens when people
are exaggerating to strengthen their case, the truth lies somewhere in
between--but nearer the optimistic extreme.
Krugman and his critics
The pessimists' case was first and most forcefully put two years ago
by Paul Krugman, an American economist at MIT. In
a provocative article called 'The Myth of the Asian Miracle` (Foreign
Affairs, Vol. 73, No.6), Mr Krugman argued that there had been no economic
miracle in East Asia. The region's growth, he said, had largely been achieved
through heavy investment and a big shift of labour from farms into factories,
rather than from productivity gains based on technological advance or organisational
change. He cheekily likened the Asian economies to the Soviet Union: once
inputs are exhausted and capital-to-output ratios rise towards rich-country
levels, diminishing returns will set in and growth will slow sharply.
Even though recent trends might appear to
confirm this thesis, Mr Krugman's argument has been ripped up at the roots
by other economists. The critics make three arguments:
Taking a breather
But even if Mr Krugman's thesis is exaggerated and even if the main
causes of the recent slowdown were cyclical, that slowdown has still exposed
several structural problems which need to be tackled if East Asia is to
sustain rapid growth. These weaknesses vary from country to country, and
are not necessarily the ones that doomsters commonly focus on.
Some economists point to rising wages and
large current-account deficits as evidence of falling competitiveness.
This is far too simplistic. Miron Mushkat, chief Asian economist of Lehman
Brothers, an American investment bank, points out that rising wages go
hand in hand with the upgrading of production in Asian economies. Higher
wages or rising exchange rates provide an incentive for firms to move into
more productive, higher-value activities. This is necessary because the
new tigers can no longer rely on cheap labour alone. With China, Vietnam
or Eastern Europe able to undercut them in labour-intensive goods, they
need to move up the ladder, from the manufacture of shirts and shoes to
things like semiconductors and consumer electronics.
But what if rising labour costs reflect overheating
or skill shortages? Some economies have indeed been overheating in recent
years, notably Malaysia and Thailand. In part the blame lies with lax monetary
policies as a result of heavy capital inflows. These have stoked up domestic
demand and pushed up wages. Likewise, current-account deficits mainly reflect
overheating rather than evidence of dwindling competitiveness or currency
overvaluation.
It is true that real exchange rates have
risen in many East Asian economies over the past couple of years as a result
of their links to the dollar and their inflation (which has been higher
than America's). The Thai baht, for example, has gained 15% in real trade-weighted
terms over the past two years. In general, though, Asian currencies are
not overvalued. Before their recent appreciation, many currencies were
significantly undervalued, and rising real exchange rates are normal for
developing countries with rapid productivity growth.
Governments' efforts to resist rises in nominal
exchange rates as foreign capital floods in are largely to blame for the
excessively loose monetary polices which caused economies to overheat a
few years ago. Governments need to shift to more flexible exchange-rate
systems to regain monetary control. For years, Singapore has successfully
followed a policy of allowing its exchange rate to appreciate.
Easy money is partly to blame for over-investment
and hence excess capacity in several areas, including semiconductors, consumer
electronics and petrochemicals. In many countries the problem has been
compounded by governments' attempts to pick winners by directing cheap
credit to favoured industries, while small firms are starved of cash. Government
meddling in capital markets is to blame for the current fragile state of
banking in almost every country in the region with the exception of Hong
Kong and Singapore. Such distortions may not matter so much in the early
stages of development, but become increasingly important as economies mature.
Infrastructure bottlenecks are widespread
because transport and power systems have failed to keep pace with industrial
expansion. An even more serious bottleneck is a shortage of skills. Thailand,
in particular, lags behind in the educational standards and skills needed
to move up the ladder to higher-tech industries. In Thailand only 38% of
14-year-olds attended school in 1993, fewer even than in China (though
recent reforms have led to children staying in school longer).
Riding the tigers
But perhaps the biggest challenge to the Asian economic miracle is
not economic but political: the risk that governments take bad policy decisions
in response to the current slowdown. Either because of lobbying by the
heads of protected industries, or because of their own unwillingness to
see growth falter, governments may be tempted to 'do something`. Last year,
for example, Malaysia hinted at import controls to help curb its current-account
deficit. That would have tackled the symptoms only, not the disease.
Both the problems and the policies will differ
from country to country. South Korea is too heavily concentrated on a few
industries, such as electronics and petrochemicals. Its economy needs to
be opened up to more competition, the power of the overweening and indebted
chaebol (conglomerates) must be reduced, and labour-and capital-market
rigidities should be relaxed. Thailand and Malaysia also need to liberalise
their financial sectors. Thailand and Indonesia need to invest more in
infrastructure. Indonesia is particularly hampered by red tape and corruption.
In contrast to South Korea, Hong Kong, Singapore
and Taiwan have flexible labour markets, less government intervention,
and small, nimble firms. Taiwan is pushing ahead with deregulation more
swiftly than South Korea; and its more flexible industrial policy is more
suited to fast changing business conditions.
To the extent that a country's long-term
growth potential depends partly upon its stage of development (see chart),
East Asian economies' growth will inevitably tend to slow. This has already
happened in the original four tigers: Hong Kong's GDP,
for example, grew by an average of 9% in the 1960s and 1970s, 7.5% in the
1980s and 5% in the 1990s.
Nevertheless, growth is likely to remain faster than industrial economies'
average of around 2.5% so long as savings remain high, economies are kept
open and education remains a priority. The original tigers are likely to
see growth slow to an average of 5-6% over the next decade. China, Malaysia,
Thailand and Indonesia should be able to grow by 7-8% over the next ten
years.
Then what? Hong Kong and Singapore are already as rich, in terms of GDP
per head, as many G7 countries. But they are special
cases: as highly sophisticated city-states, they might well be able to
enjoy higher growth rates and overtake America's income per head. After
all, Hamburg has an income per head 60% above the United States, even though
the figure for Germany overall is 20% below America.
Indeed, there is no theoretical reason why
in the longer term some other East Asian economies cannot overtake income
levels in America and Europe, even as their growth rates slow, by making
even better use of the latest technology. The UBS
study points to experience in rich economies which suggests that inventing
new technology may be less important than being quick to adopt the best
available technology across all sectors. The bank suggests that the slowdown
in growth in rich economies is partly explained by policies which subsidise
or protect sunset industries or tax policies that distort capital and labour
costs, rather than a shortage of new technologies. If (a big if) East Asian
economies avoid these pitfalls, some of them might one day overtake the
rich West.
* 'The Asian Economic Miracle`, UBS International Finance,
Issue 29, Autumn 1996.
(*) 'Growth and Productivity in ASEAN
Economies`, presented at an IMF conference in Jakarta, November 1996.
© Copyright 1997 The Economist Newspaper Limited. All Rights Reserved